Théorie des jeux: working papers (RePEc, 22/11/2010)

Source : NEP (New Economics Papers) | RePEc

  • Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game
Date: 2010-06
By: Parkash Chander (National University of Singapore and CORE, Universite Catholique de Louvain)
Myrna Wooders (Department of Economics, Vanderbilt University)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:van:wpaper:1008&r=gth
This paper brings together two of the most important solution concepts of game theory –subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium of a non-cooperative game and the core of a cooperativegame. Our approach rests on two fundamental ideas: (1) Given an extensive game, the formationof a coalition leads to a new game where all the members of the coalition become one player. (2)At the origin of any subgame, the only possible coalitions consist of players who have decision nodes in the subgame. We introduce a concept of subgame perfect cooperative equilibrium, which we label the gamma-core of an extensive game. We provide a necessary and sufficient condition for the existence of the gamma-core of an extensive game of perfect information. As a motivating example, we formulate the problem of global warming as a dynamic game with simultaneous moves and show that if the payoff functions are quadratic, then the gamma-core of the game is nonem pty.
Keywords: subgame perfect cooperation, extensive form game, subgame perfection, gamma-core
JEL: C72
  • Perfect Regular Equilibrium
Date: 2010-10-09
By: hanjoon michael, jung/j
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:26534&r=gth
We propose a revised version of the perfect Bayesian equilibrium in general multi-period games with observed actions. In finite games, perfect Bayesian equilibria are weakly consistent and subgame perfect Nash equilibria. In general games that allow a continuum of types and strategies, however, perfect Bayesian equilibria might not satisfy these criteria of rational solution concepts. To solve this problem, we revise the definition of the perfect Bayesian equilibrium by replacing Bayes’ rule with a regular conditional probability. We call this revised solution concept a perfect regular equilibrium. Perfect regular equilibria are always weakly consistent and subgame perfect Nash equilibria in general games. In addition, perfect regular equilibria are equivalent to simplified perfect Bayesian equilibria in finite games. Therefore, the perfect regular equilibrium is an extended and simple version of the perfect Bayesian equi librium in general multi-period games with observed actions.
Keywords: Bayes’ rule; general Multi-period game; Perfect Bayesian equilibrium; Perfect regular equilibrium; Regular conditional probability; Solution concept.
JEL: C72
  • The Lorenz-maximal core allocations and the kernel in some classes of assignment games
Date: 2010
By: Francesc Llerena
Marina Nunez
Carles Rafels (Universitat de Barcelona)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:bar:bedcje:2010246&r=gth
Keywords: core, assignment game, lorenz domination, kernel
JEL: C71
  • On the number of blocks required to access the core
Date: 2010-11-09
By: Béal, Sylvain
Rémila, Eric
Solal, Philippe
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:26578&r=gth
For any transferable utility game in coalitional form with nonempty core, we show that that the number of blocks required to switch from an imputation out of the core to an imputation in the core is less than or equal to n(n-1)/2, where n is the cardinality of the player set. This number considerably improves the upper bounds found so far by Koczy (2006) and Yang (2010). Our result relies on an altered version of the procedure proposed by Sengupta and Sengupta (1996). The use of the Davis-Maschler reduced-games is also pointed out.
Keywords: Core; excess function; dominance path; Davis-Maschler reduced-game
JEL: C71
  • Tree-Type Values for Cycle-Free Directed Graph Games
Date: 2010
By: Khmelnitskaya, A.
Talman, A.J.J. (Tilburg University, Center for Economic Research)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dgr:kubcen:2010113&r=gth
Mathematics Subject Classification 2000: 91A12, 91A43
Keywords: TU game;cooperation structure;Myerson value;efficiency;deletion link property;stability
JEL: C71
  • The Core of an Extended Tree Game: A New Characterisation
Date: 2010-11
By: Barbara von Schnurbein
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rwi:repape:0212&r=gth
Cost allocation problems on networks can be interpreted as cooperative games on a graph structure. In the classical standard tree game, the cost of a service delivered, by a source has to be allocated between homogeneous users at the vertices. But, modern networks have also the capacity to supply different (levels of) services. For example, a cable network that provides diff erent television standards. Users that choose different levels of service can not be treated equally. The extended tree game accounts for such differences between users. Here, players are characterised by their level of demand, consequently the implications on the cost structure of the problem can be considered. We show how an ET-game can be formulated as the sum of unanimity games. This observation enables us to directly calculate the weighted Shapley values and to identify the core of an ET-game.
Keywords: Cooperative game theory; extended tree game; core
JEL: C71
  • Strategic experimentation with Poisson bandits..
Date: 2010
By: Keller, Godfrey
Rady, Sven
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ner:oxford:http://economics.ouls.ox.ac.uk/14975/&r=gth
We study a game of strategic experimentation with two-armed bandits where the risky arm distributes lump-sum payoffs according to a Poisson process. Its intensity is either high or low, and unknown to the players. We consider Markov perfect equilibria with beliefs as the state variable and show that all such equilibria exhibit an “encouragement effect” relative to the single-agent optimum. There is no equilibrium in which all players use cutoff strategies. Owing to the encouragement effect, asymmetric equilibria in which players take turns playing the risky arm before all experimentation stops Pareto dominate the unique symmetric equilibrium. Rewarding the last experimenter with a higher continuation value increases the range of beliefs where players experiment, but may reduce the intensity of experimentation at more optimistic beliefs. This suggests that there is no equilibrium that uniformly maximizes the players’ a verage payoff.
JEL: D83
  • Sending Information to Interactive Receivers Playing a Generalized Prisoners Dilemma
Date: 2010
By: Kfir Eliaz
Roberto Serrano
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:bro:econwp:2010-16&r=gth
Consider the problem of information disclosure for a planner who faces two agents interacting in a state-dependent multi-action prisoners?dilemma. We ?nd conditions under which the planner can make use of his superior information by disclosing some of it to the agents, and conditions under which such information leakage is not possible. Although the problem is entirely symmetric, the planner?s only way to reveal part of the information is based on creating asymmetries between the two agents by giving them di¤erent pieces of information. We also ? nd conditions under which such partially informative equilibria are the planner?s best equilibria.
Keywords: Information Disclosure; Generalized Prisoners Dilemma; Uninformative Equilibria; Partially or Fully Informative Equilibria
  • Strategic Network Interdiction
Date: 2010-06
By: Sunghoon Hong (Department of Economics, Vanderbilt University)
Myrna Wooders (Department of Economics, Vanderbilt University)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:van:wpaper:1010&r=gth
We develop a strategic model of network interdiction in a non-cooperative game of flow. A security agency operates a network with arc capacities. An adversary, endowed with a bounded quantity of bads, chooses a flow that specifies a plan for carrying bads through the network from a base to a target. Simultaneously, the agency chooses a blockage, which specifies a plan for blocking the transport of bads through arcs in the network. However, the blockage of arcs disrupts the operation of the network. The adversary gains and the agency loses from the target damage and the network disruption. The adversary incurs the expense of carrying bads. We characterize the Nash equilibria in terms of the primitives of our model. Our model contributes to the literature of game theory by introducing non-cooperative behavior into a Kalai-Zemel type mode of a (cooperative) game of flow. Our research also advances models and results on netwo rk interdiction.
Keywords: Network interdiction, Noncooperative game of flow, Blockage, Nash equilibrium, Kalai- Zemel game of flow
JEL: C72
  • Community Structure and Market Outcomes: A Repeated Games in Networks Approach
Date: 2010
By: Itay Fainmesser
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:bro:econwp:2010-14&r=gth
Consider a large market with asymmetric information, in which sellers choose whether to cooperate or deviate and ?cheat?their buyers, and buyers decide whether to re-purchase from di¤erent sellers. We model active trade relationships as links in a buyer-seller network and suggest a framework for studying repeated games in such networks. In our framework, buyers and sellers have rich yet incomplete knowledge of the network structure; allowing us to derive meaningful conditions that determine whether a network is consistent with trade and cooperation between every buyer and seller that are connected. We show that three network features reduce the minimal discount factor necessary for sustaining cooperation: moderate competition, sparseness, and segregation. We ? nd that the incentive constraints rule out networks that maximize the volume of trade and that the constrained trade maximizing networks are in between ?old world? segregated and sparse networks, and a ?global market?
Keywords: Buyer-Seller networks; repeated games; moral hazard;asymmetric information; trust; cooperation; institutions
  • Make Him an Offer He Can’t Refuse: Avoiding Conflicts through Side Payments
Date: 2010
By: Erik O. Kimbrough (Department of Economics (AE1), School of Business and Economics, Maastricht University)
Roman Sheremeta (Argyros School of Business and Economics, Chapman University)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:chu:wpaper:10-23&r=gth
The equilibrium of a two-stage conflict game with side-payments predicts that with binding stage-one offers, proposers make and responders accept side-payments, generating settlements that strongly favor proposers. When side-payments are non-binding, proposers offer nothing and conflicts always arise. Laboratory experiments confirm that binding side-payments reduce conflicts. However, 30% of responders reject binding offers, and offers are more egalitarian than predicted. Surprisingly, non-binding side-payments also improve efficiency, although less than binding. With binding side-payments, 98% of efficiency gains come from avoided conflicts. However, with non-binding side-payments, only 49% of gains come from avoided conflicts and 51% from reduced conflict expenditures.
Keywords: contest, conflict resolution, side payments, experiments
JEL: C72
  • Group strategy-proof social choice functions with binary ranges and arbitrary domains: characterization results
Date: 2010-04-28
By: Salvador Barberà
Dolors Berga
Bernardo Moreno
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:aub:autbar:853.10&r=gth
We define different concepts of group strategy-proofness for social choice functions. We discuss the connections between the defined concepts under different assumptions on their domains of definition. We characterize the social choice functions that satisfy each one of them and whose ranges consist of two alternatives, in terms of two types of basic properties.
Keywords: Social choice functions, Binary ranges, group strategy-proofness, xy-monotonicity, xy-based rules.
JEL: D71
  • The Effect of Entitlements and Equality on Cooperative Bargaining with Private, Unverifiable Information
Date: 2010-11-04
By: Christopher Bruce
Jeremy Clark (University of Canterbury)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cbt:econwp:10/68&r=gth
In many bargaining situations a third party is authorized to impose a backstop position on the bargainers. Prominent examples include governments who use collaborative policymaking between stakeholders to set public policy, but also compulsory arbitration in labour negotiations. Axiomatic models of cooperative bargaining, such as the Nash bargain, presume that the status quo allocation will have no effect on the outcome parties reach if it differs from the backstop set by the third party. In contrast, experimental findings have suggested that both equality of outcomes and entitlement (where the status quo establishes a focal point) may affect the agreements bargainers reach, at least under full information. This paper extends the investigation of the effect of equality and entitlement on cooperative bargaining to the case where parties have private, unverifiable information concerning the value of outcomes. We use a two-p arty, two-attribute experimental design in which subjects take part in unstructured, face-to-face bargaining to jointly select from among approximately 200 potential outcomes. We find that, relative to full information, parties who bargain under private information are almost as likely to reach agreements as those under full information, and that these agreements are still approximately Pareto efficient. Further, the effect of the status quo (rather than backstop) allocation seems amplified under private information, while the effect of equality is dampened, but not eliminated.
Keywords: cooperative bargaining; private information; Nash bargain; egalitarian; entitlement; fairness; focal points
JEL: C92
  • Why are Trade Agreements Regional?
Date: 2010-03
By: Ben Zissimos (Department of Economics, Vanderbilt University)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:van:wpaper:1002&r=gth
This paper shows how distance may be used to coordinate on a unique equilibrium in which trade agreements are regional. Trade agreement formation is modeled as coalition formation. In a standard trade model with no distance between countries a familiar problem of coordination failure occurs, giving rise to multiple equilibria; any one of many possible trade agreements can form. With distance between countries, regional trade agreements generate larger rent-shifting effects than non-regional agreements. Countries use these effects to coordinate on a unique equilibrium.
Keywords: Coalition, coordination, regionalism, preferential trade agreement, trade liberalization
JEL: F02
  • How Optimism Leads to Price Discovery and Efficiency in a Dynamic Matching Market
Date: 2010-10-22
By: Dipjyoti Majumdar (Concordia University)
Artyom Shneyerov (Concordia University)
Huan Xie (Concordia University)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:crd:wpaper:10004&r=gth
We study a market search equilibrium with aggregate uncertainty, private information and heterogeneus beiefs. Traders initially start out optimistic and then update their beliefs based on their matching experience in the market, using the Bayes rule. It is shown that all separating equilibria converge to perfect competition in the limit as the time between matches tends to 0. We also establish existence of a separating equilibrium.
Keywords: Markets with search frictions, aggregate uncertainty, heterogeneous beliefs, optimism, bargaining, foundations of Walrasian equilibrium
JEL: C73
  • Does the Endowment of Contributors Make a Difference in Threshold Public Good Games?
Date: 2010-10
By: Federica Alberti
Edward J. Cartwright
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ukc:ukcedp:1009&r=gth
We investigate experimentally whether the endowment of potential contributors changes the success rate of providing threshold public goods. We find a U shaped relationship in which the success rate is relatively high when the endowment is either relatively small or large. We also find an inverted U shaped relationship in terms of the variance of contributions. This suggests that people find it hardest to coordinate and provide threshold public goods when endowments are of ‘intermediate’ size. By this we mean that the endowment is small enough that people do need to contribute relatively a lot to fund the good, but is also large enough that no one person is critical in providing the good. Coordinating is difficult in this case because there is an incentive to free ride and the possibility to do so creating a conflict of interest.
Keywords: Public Good; Threshold; Endowment
JEL: C72

Laisser un commentaire

Entrez vos coordonnées ci-dessous ou cliquez sur une icône pour vous connecter:

Logo WordPress.com

Vous commentez à l'aide de votre compte WordPress.com. Déconnexion / Changer )

Image Twitter

Vous commentez à l'aide de votre compte Twitter. Déconnexion / Changer )

Photo Facebook

Vous commentez à l'aide de votre compte Facebook. Déconnexion / Changer )

Photo Google+

Vous commentez à l'aide de votre compte Google+. Déconnexion / Changer )

Connexion à %s